The Covid-19 lockdown provided opportunities for enterprising people to circumvent the often irrational bans on everything from can openers to cigarettes. By doing so, they served a moral purpose. Black markets have always served to keep government in check.

Prejudice against smugglers is almost universal. Most people simply dismiss smuggling as a crime. But ask them what exactly smugglers do that is so bad, and few will be able to explain their position in great detail.

Black markets exist because there is a demand for goods or services that are otherwise prohibited by government, or are heavily taxed. In a few cases, the prohibition might be justified, but usually, it is not.

Consider, for example, the prohibition on so-called ‘non-essential’ goods during South Africa’s hard lockdown, or the lengthy prohibition on alcohol and tobacco, neither of which served much purpose.

Black markets during lockdown

It is thanks to smugglers that most smokers in South Africa were able to continue smoking, despite government’s diktat that this simple pleasure should be denied them. Most managed to avoid the severe withdrawal symptoms that would have made coping with the isolation and loss of income due to draconian and irrational lockdown regulations that much harder.

The irritability that comes with withdrawal can be explosive, and increase the incidence of domestic unhappiness and even violence. For many people with mental health issues, as well as recovering addicts, smoking is an invaluable crutch that keeps them sane and sober. It is thanks to smugglers that the negative impact of the tobacco ban wasn’t much, much worse.

As it turned out, smoking proved to be somewhat protective against Covid-19, so whichever way you look at it, cigarette smugglers did both smokers and public healthcare a favour.

The black market in alcohol and tobacco also provided income opportunities for many thousands of South Africans who were unceremoniously prohibited from earning a living, in the speculative hope that condemning people to debt default and starvation would somehow save lives.

I have friends in the tourism and entertainment industry, many working informally and therefore ineligible for any government-funded relief, whose only source of income since the start of lockdown was sourcing and distributing black market goods.

‘Tax morality’

Many opponents of smuggling will say that they merely avoid paying taxes, and that that is bad. This is a sore point not only for government officials who are denied the taxes, but also for competitors who pay the taxes legally required of them.

The government likes to talk of ‘tax morality’. This term is intended to imply that paying taxes is, ipso facto, moral. This should be far from a settled matter, however.

What is moral about an arbitrary tax on specific goods or services? Why should government take a cut when someone, say, imports inexpensive clothing from Vietnam? Why should government tax alcohol or tobacco?

The argument that import taxes protect local industry is weak. What they do is protect inefficient local industry from competition. This harms consumers. When the poor need to pay 40% more for clothes, just to keep a few inefficient and failing local textile producers in business, is that moral?

Consider the television licence, which is a tax levied on everyone who has ever owned a television, supposedly to fund a moribund and bankrupt state broadcaster. What is moral about TV licences? Why do we even need a state broadcaster, when private alternatives can offer news and entertainment that is better and independent of government propaganda?

That sin taxes protect public health by reducing consumption is also a weak argument. Consumption of products like alcohol and tobacco is notoriously inelastic. The price of these products may affect the behaviour of occasional smokers, or moderate drinkers, but it does little to affect the behaviour of habitual, heavy drinkers or smokers.

The total prohibition of these products, and the exorbitant black market prices smokers and drinkers were prepared to pay to sustain their habit, demonstrates just how ineffective sin taxes really are.

Why is it moral, in any case, for government to protect people from their own lifestyle choices?

Even in cases where the prohibitions seem justified, such as hard drugs, what have they really achieved? Violent criminal enterprises have been enriched, as have corrupt government officials. Drug users have been impoverished, and lives have been unnecessarily ruined by incarceration or the threat of prosecution. All this has had minimal, if any, effect on the prevalence of drug use, while making drugs less safe for users.

Before governments started to ban hard drugs around the turn of the last century, was the world mired in crushing epidemics of drug abuse? No, it wasn’t. Drug abuse was a marginal problem.

Big picture on tax

When person A produces a good or service that person B is willing to pay for, by what right does government intervene and levy a tax on the transaction, so that person A will sell less, and person B has to pay a higher price? That surely makes everyone worse off?

The bigger picture does not improve the case for taxes much. It is true that even a minimal government requires some tax revenue in order to provide the basic services needed to protect life, liberty and property.

Such taxes can best be levied as a simple flat tax on income, or a consumption tax. Milton Friedman’s negative income tax is a great model that provides a social safety net without unduly distorting economic activity, and without necessarily involving government in the provision of all sorts of social services.

However, modern governments don’t just raise the minimum taxes they need. They raise as much tax as they possibly can. Tax-and-spend is how most governments justify their existence.

They promise voters more free stuff than their opponents do, in order to win power. The most important aspect of that power is the control of the public purse. Once they gain control of the public purse, they spend tax revenue in ways that benefit their friends, families, supporters and constituents, building a corrupt patronage network that, they hope, will strengthen their continued grip on power.

Although this process has always been a feature of public politics, at every time, and everywhere in the world, South Africa has recently suffered an extraordinary amount of public corruption.

When taxes are wasted on dysfunctional state-owned enterprises, on corrupt private interests, on inefficient government services, and on personal enrichment of politicians, where does that leave ‘tax morality’?

When economic activity gets depressed by government policies, yet government wants to pay for its policies by raising yet more taxes, how is this moral?

Neither excessive taxation nor misspent taxation is moral. It is hypocritical of government officials to talk about ‘tax morality’ as if the desire not to be taxed to pay for corrupt and inefficient government is somehow a failing on the part of citizens. Resenting – or avoiding – excessive and misspent taxation is perfectly natural, and in many cases, perfectly just.

Minimising black markets

A great test for how honest, fair and efficient governments are lies in whether they order affairs in such a way that they provide minimal incentives to smugglers.

When taxes are reasonable and government works well, there simply won’t be much for smugglers to do. Black markets almost always arise as a result of irrational, ineffective or counter-productive taxes or prohibitions.

Those smugglers can play a tremendous role in protecting people from their governments, and in helping them to develop and thrive despite their government’s misguided economic policies, corruption, or other failures.

Good arguments can be made that smugglers and pirates helped spark Britain’s industrial revolution, and that illicit trade made America the success it is today.

In both cases, they counteracted the harmful impacts of prohibitions, colonial trade restrictions, protective tariffs, and excessive taxation.

Black market smugglers introduced economic liberalism to these countries before their governments were forced to adopt economic liberalism as the norm, leading to the greatest improvement in public welfare in recorded history.

Producing the things that meet the needs and wants of consumers is a moral good. That production will happen, whether or not government intervenes. If government imposes too heavy a burden on legal trade, producers and distributors will find illicit means of satisfying consumer demand.

Contrary to popular belief, they’re not wrong to do so, since it limits the extent to which governments can restrict trade and confiscate wealth for its own purposes.

Smugglers have always kept a check on the abuse of government power to direct production, restrict trade and impose excessive taxes. By doing so, smugglers serve a great moral purpose.

So let’s hear it for the smugglers, the illicit producers, and the black market traders.

The views of the writer are not necessarily the views of the Daily Friend or the IRR

If you like what you have just read, subscribe to the Daily Friend


contributor

Ivo Vegter is a freelance journalist, columnist and speaker who loves debunking myths and misconceptions, and addresses topics from the perspective of individual liberty and free markets.